Next year will see the start of two major legacies of New Labour
social policy: NEST and compulsion. Taken together, they are intended
to ensure that all employees have some form of pension provision over
and above the increasingly paltry provisions of the state pension and
associated means-tested benefits. The latter is simply the concept that
all employers must enrol all employees in a pension scheme. It is then
up to the employees to opt out of that scheme, which they are less
likely to do. NEST is the vehicle created to be the scheme for employers
who do not already have pension scheme provision: an ultra low cost
Defined Contribution (DC) scheme, designed to be simple and cheap.
Both
these things are laudable in their intention. In the scramble to
condemn the baby-boomers for bankrupting the state and all the good
private sector pension schemes, we tend to forget that a good number of
them will spend their retirements in poverty, reliant on the
means-tested state benefits that are the pensioner equivalent of the
dole. If the wealthiest generation in history has these problems,
imagine what it will be like for the rest of us. So the idea of pushing
us all towards making our own pension provision, and making it cheaper
and easier to do so is a good one. Such savings would be inherently
ours, whilst still subject to the rules governing all pensions: chiefly
that they cannot be drawn until age 55. Beyond that, they would operate
in much the same way as any other DC pension or investment. This, of
course, is where the problems start.
As the startling hubris of
pension scheme actuaries - convinced that market returns of 9% a year
would be an everlasting constant - led to the closure of ever more Final
Salary pension schemes, the only significant alternative has been the
DC pension scheme, which is effectively just an investment vehicle that
has restrictions on when and how you can access the invested money. How
and why this should have become the preferred form of pension provision
is perhaps a discussion for another day, but it is worth noting that
whilst invested, most of the money is held by an insurance company, and
in order to avoid punitive tax charges, 75% of this money has to be paid
to an insurance company at retirement. I guess that's just a
coincidence.
Whatever the reasons for its popularity, the DC
scheme is now the norm. Chances are, if you have any sort of pension
provision, you're in a DC scheme. I wonder how often you check the
performance of your chosen investments. I work in the financial services
sector and I don't do it more than about once a year. I mean, that's
not really a problem: I'm in this for the long run, so the last thing I
want to do is start to panic about short term fluctuations in equities,
bonds or even the price of gold. In the long term the trend is always
upwards. Except of course that it isn't: at several points in the last
twenty years index linked investments would have made a loss when
adjusted for inflation if drawn at the 'wrong' time. Various schemes
have various vehicles to avoid 'the wrong time' being when you happen to
need or want retire, such as 'lifestyling' or offering funds run by a
fund manager who is supposed to be able to get better than index linked
returns on your investments, although such things invariably incur an
additional annual charge that eats away at that extra interest. So, even
though massive returns on investments are not forthcoming, the models
used to predict how much money is needed to fund a comfortable
retirement still assume year on year investment growth of 7% against a
rate of inflation of 2.5%. Anyone who's paid even scant attention to
inflation over the last few years will know that it has only been at or
below 2.5% for 7 of the last 20 years (based on September RPI values).
This means that the statutory model for calculating potential retirement
provision is about as realistic as the actuarial projections that
allowed companies to take 'contribution holidays' from their final
salary pension schemes back in the 80s and 90s, ensuring the death of
those shemes. However, the government is reluctant to change the
assumptions used in the model to more pessimistic (or realistic) ones
for fear that it will engender a sense of futility in savers and cause
people to give up on pension saving altogether rather than scare them
into saving more. Of course in the case of NEST, the impetus to invest
more is not there, as it is not going to be possible to do so. Why this
should be so is unclear, as it would seem to remove another option to
plan seriously for retirement. It seems that the hope is that once in
one scheme, people will see the benefits of investing in their future
and start another pension scheme with an insurer. No really.
|
Hmm, not bad... |
|
Hmm, not so good... |
|
Better than stuffing it under your mattress. |
|
Sometimes better than stuffing it under your mattress. |
NEST
does not have managed funds because it is designed to cost the minimum
for the members. The notion behind this is commendable in that no one
should be compelled to pay for the profits of the fund managers,
especially when there is no guarantee of a return. However, what it also
means is that we all have to effectively become our own fund managers,
suddenly realising in our lunchbreaks that the time to sell Pacific
equities is now and giving NEST a call to move the lot to European
bonds. This sounds very glamorous, but the reality is mundane, and if it
is a scheme for people who weren't interested in pension provision in
the first place, what is the likelihood that they will suddenly find the
interest to get actively involved in making that pension better? I
suppose it is possible that some people will, on finding their money is
inaccessible take an interest in playing the markets: it's just possible
that people will find out that it really doesn't take much to be a
Master of the Universe.
Of course what is more likely is that
people will be encouraged to invest in 'safer' funds: these
traditionally being things like government bonds. Obviously in the case
of many governments, such investments have recently become considerably
more risky, although that does also mean the long term yields are up.
This would be good for the people who have invested in them, but not so
good for the tax payers saddled with the extra cost of paying off their
country's debts.
So let's think about this a bit more in terms of
NEST. This means that the government has set up a pension scheme in
which you could invest in the government's debt via an insurance
company. Why via an insurance company? Why doesn't NEST buy bonds
direct? We have National Savings, why don't we just run NEST in a
similar manner? Oh, I forgot, someone has to make a profit out of your
welfare: god forbid you invest in your general wellbeing without paying
some superannuated waster for the privilege. Let us not forget, in the
business of your future wellbeing just who is lobbying on your behalf.
The people whose interest is the status quo that they generated must
surely be interested in alternatives that might further benefit you and
your government at the expense of their profit, mustn't they? What else
could they possibly want?
No comments:
Post a Comment